Money and Trading 101
Guest Author: Stephanie Kelton, cross posted from Global Economic Intersection. (See ‘About the Author’ at end of article.)
Editor’s note: This article is based on two blog posts at New Economic Perspectives, which ran under the title "What Happens When the Government Tightens its Belt?" – Part I and Part II.
There is a direct relationship between what’s happening in the private sector and what’s happening in the public sector. But the relationship is not the one that some would have you believe. Those beliefs contradict some simple mathematical facts. And I want you to understand the facts.
Imagine two people sitting on opposite ends of a 15-foot teeter-totter. The laws of physics dictate that the seesaw will balance if the product of the first mass (w1) and its distance (d1) from the fulcrum (i.e. the balancing point) is equal to the product of the other mass (w2) and its distance (d2) from the fulcrum. Thus, the physicist can show that the teeter-totter will be in balance when the fulcrum is placed 6 feet from the end holding a 150lb person and 9 feet from the end holding a 100lb person. Moreover, the laws of physics ensure that an imbalance will arise if the mass or the relative position of one of the people is changed.
The laws of accounting allow us to demonstrate that similarly powerful concepts apply to the science of economics. Beginning with the simple identity for GDP in a closed economy, we have:
[1] Y = C + I + G, where:
Y = GDP = National Income
C = Aggregate Consumption Expenditure
I = Aggregate Investment Expenditure
G = Aggregate Government Expenditure
For economists, this is as obvious as stating that a linear foot is the sum of 12 sequential inches. It simply recognizes that the total amount of money spent buying newly produced goods and services will yield an equivalent income to the sellers of these products. Thus, it demonstrates that expenditures are a source of income.
Once earned, income can be allocated in one of three ways. At the end of the day, all income (Y) will be spent (C), saved (S) or used in payment of taxes (T):
[2] Y = C + S + T
Since they are equivalent expressions for Y, we can set equation [1] equal to equation [2], giving us:
C + I + G = C + S + T
Or, after canceling (C) from both sides and moving terms around:
[3] (S – I) = (G – T)
Equation [3] shows that there is a direct relationship between what’s happening in the private sector (S – I) and what’s happening in the public sector (G – T). But it is not the one that Pete Peterson, Erskin Bowles, or President Obama would have you believe. And I want you to understand why they are wrong.
A Balanced Budget
To understand the argument, imagine that you and Uncle Sam are sitting on opposite ends of a teeter-totter. You represent the private sector, and your financial status is given by (S – I). Your budget can be in balance (S = I), in deficit (S < I) or in surplus (S > I). When your financial status is positive (S > I), you are net saving. When your financial status is negative (S < I), you are net borrowing. Uncle Sam’s financial status is equal to (G – T), and, like yours, his budget may be balanced (G = T), in deficit (G > T) or in surplus (G < T). When you interact, only three outcomes are possible.
First, it is conceivable that (S = I) and (G = T) so that (S – I) = 0 and (G – T) = 0. When this condition holds, the teeter-totter will level off with each of you experiencing a balanced budget.
In the above scenario, the government is balancing its receipts (T) and expenditures (G), and you are balancing your savings and investment spending. There is no net gain/loss.
Government Deficits
But suppose the government begins to spend more than it collects in taxes (i.e. G > T). How will Uncle Sam’s deficit affect your position on the teeter-totter? The answer is as straightforward as increasing the mass of the person on the right-hand side of the seesaw. As Uncle Sam’s financial position turns negative, your financial position turns positive.
This should make intuitive as well as mathematical sense, because when Uncle Sam runs a deficit, you receive more financial assets than you lose through taxation. Put simply, Uncle Sam’s deficit lifts you into a surplus position. Moreover, bigger deficits mean bigger surpluses for you.
Austerity
Finally, let’s see what happens when Uncle Sam tightens his belt. Suppose, for example, that we were able to duplicate the much-coveted surpluses of 1999-2001. What would (and did!) happen to the private sector’s financial position?
Because the economy’s financial flows are a closed system – every payment must come from somewhere and end up somewhere – one sector’s surplus is always the other sector’s deficit. As the government “tightens” its belt, it “lightens” its load on the teeter-totter, shifting the relative burden onto you.
This is not rocket science, but it appears to befuddle scores of educated people, including President Obama, who said, “small businesses and families are tightening their belts. Their government should, too.” This kind of rhetoric may temporarily boost his approval ratings, but the policy itself will undermine the efforts of the very families and small businesses that are trying to improve their financial positions.
Ruffled Feathers
This accounting truism has ruffled the feathers of a flock of readers who have been programmed to launch into an anti-government tirade at the mere mention of the public sector and to regard the dangers of deficit spending as an unimpeachable fact. And while you’re certainly entitled to your own political views, you are not, as Senator Moynihan famously said, entitled to your own facts.
The Global Economy
How do the financial flows that occur in an open economy impact the previous discussion of a closed economy? This questions leads to analysis of the more realistic open-economy in which we actually live.
In an open economy, income flows into and out of the domestic economy as residents and foreigners buy goods and services (exports minus imports), make and receive payments such as interest and dividends (factor income) and make net transfer payments (such as foreign aid). Each country keeps track of these payments using a balance of payments(BOP) account, which summarizes the international monetary transactions that take place between the home country and the rest of the world. The BOP has two primary components – the current account and the capital account – and we can use either one to show whether, on balance, money is flowing into or out of a country.
When we incorporate these international flows, we transform the closed-economy accounting identity used previously:
[1] Domestic Private Surplus = Government Deficit
into the open-economy accounting identity shown below:
[2] Domestic Private = Government + Current Account
Surplus Deficit Balance
or, equivalently,
[3] Domestic Private = Government + Capital Account
Surplus Surplus Balance
Positive Current Account Balance
When the current account balance is positive, it means that we in the private sector (households and domestic firms) are accumulating net financial claims on foreigners. When it is negative, they are accumulating net financial claims on us. Thus, a positive current account implies a negative capital account and vice versa.
To see this in the context of the teeter-totter model, let’s initially hold the public sector’s balance constant at zero (i.e. let’s assume the government is balancing its budget so that G = T). With the government budget in balance, Uncle Sam is a “weightless” entity on the teeter-totter, so that the private sector’s financial position will simply reflect the “weight” of the capital account. Suppose, first, that the current account is in surplus (i.e. the capital account shows an equivalent deficit):
The image above depicts the benefit (to the private sector) of a current account surplus (a.k.a a capital account deficit), and it is the outcome that many of you accused me of sidestepping in my previous post. Of course, the U.S. does not have a current account surplus, so let’s address that point before moving on. (And lest anyone begin to hyperventilate, I’ll also address the fact that G ? T). First, the current account.
Negative Current Account Balance
Sticking with (G = T) for the moment, we can show how a current account deficit impacts the private sector’s financial position. As the capital account moves from deficit (diagram above) into surplus (diagram below), we see that the private sector’s financial position moves from surplus into deficit.
Fact Check
But does this all of this hold true in the real world, or is it some kind of economic chicanery? Let’s check the facts.
Equations [2] and [3] above are not based on economic theory. They are accounting identities that always “add up” in the real world. So let’s firm up the discussion about the implications of government “belt tightening” by running through some examples using the real world data found in the table below (Hat tip to Scott Fullwilir for sharing the file. All of the data comes from the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) and the Flow of Funds.)
[ Click here for Sectoral Balances Data (.xlsx format) ]
Let’s begin with the data from 1998 (Q3), when the public sector deficit was just 0.01% of GDP and the current account deficit was 2.56% of GDP. Plugging these numbers into equation [2] above, the identity tells us (and the data in the table confirm) that the private sector’s balance must have been:
[2] Domestic Private Sector’s Balance = 0.01% + (-2.56% )= -2.55%
Here, we can see that the private sector’s financial position was deteriorating because it was making large (net) payments to foreigners. Because this loss of financial resources was not offset by the public sector, the private sector’s financial position deteriorated.
To see how a bigger government deficit would have improved the private sector’s financial position, let’s look at the data from 1988 (Q1). As a percent of GDP, the current account balance was 2.59%, nearly the same as before, while the government’s deficit came in at a much higher 4.2% of GDP. We can use Equation [2] to see effect of the larger budget deficit:
[2] Domestic Private Sector’s Balance = 4.2% + (-2.59%) = 1.61%
In this period, the private sector ends up with a surplus because the government’s deficit was large enough to more than offset the negative effect of the current account deficit.
Again, this is simply a property of the sectoral balance sheet identities. Whenever the government’s deficit is too small to offset a deficit in the current account, the private sector will experience a net loss. The result my ruffle your feathers, but it is an unimpeachable fact.
Conclusion
So let’s go back to President Obama’s comment and the reason I wrote this article in the first place. The President said:
“[S]mall businesses and families are tightening their belts. Their government should, too.”
Wrong! When we tighten our belts, it means that we are trying to build up our savings. We do this by spending less. But spending drives our economy. Sales create jobs. So unless Obama has a secret plan to reverse three decades of current account deficits, the Government needs to loosen its belt when we tighten ours. If it doesn’t, then millions of us will lose our shirts.
Author’s comment: I am aware that I have said nothing about the usefulness of the spending projects, the waste and inefficiency that exists with many government programs, cronyism, inequality, etc., etc. These are legitimate and important questions, but they are not the focus of this analysis. I wrote this series of blogs to try to get people to understand the interplay between the private, public and foreign sectors’ balance sheets. Criticizing me for not addressing a myriad of other issues is like reading Old Yeller and complaining, “What about the cat? You’ve completely ignored the genus Felis!”
Related Articles
The Great Debate©: Does QE Prevent Recession or Cause It? by John Lounsbury
Savings Rate Disparities by Michael Pettis
Modeling a Multisector Economy by Steve Keen
The Global Financial Crisis is Not Behind Us by Steve Keen
Budget Balancing: Heads You Lose, Tails You Lose by Steven Hansen
Is a Budget Deficit Necessary for an Economy? by Steven Hansen
Is Ignorance Bliss? A Look at U.S. Income Inequality by Elliott Morss
From Stimulus to Austerity – What Role for Taxes? by Elliott Morss
Inequality, Leverage and Crisis by Michael Kunhof and Romain Ranciere
Austerity Rather than Stimulus? Wait a Minute! by Elliott Morss
Devil’s Bargain by William H. Gross
The New Feudalism by Derryl Hermanutz
Sophie’s Choice for the EU by Dirk Ehnts
Does Germany have to have Net exports to Bail-out the Periphery? by Dirk Ehnts
Fall of the New Monetary Consensus by L. Randall Wray
Eurozone Crises left to Fester by Daniel Gros
The Eurozone in Bad Need of a Psychiatrist by Stefano Micossi
Eurozone – Caught in a Financial – Sovereign Web by Clive Corcoran
The Rough Politics of European Adjustment by Michael Pettis
About the Author
Stephanie Kelton is Associate Professor of Economics at the University of Missouri-Kansas City, Research Scholar at The Levy Economics Institute and Director of Graduate Student Research at the Center for Full Employment and Price Stability. Her research expertise is in: Federal Reserve operations, fiscal policy, Social Security, health care, international finance and employment policy. She writes at New Economic Perspectives. Full bio is available here.
What I would like to see in the analysis of accounting identities that would make this whole concept easier for me to grasp is debt.
The analysis equates money flows between “taxpayers” and “government” as if money is not going anywhere else – and I don’t mean foreign exchange. If “taxpayers” in general were paying out 2K (housing and other consumables) with an income of 1K, and that is unsustainable, why exactly is the government paying out more than income sustainable? Is there a profound difference between public versus private debt? Is a public default worse, better, or no different than a private default (I am hard pressed to know the difference between a public and private default anyway, as government policy is obviously TBTF).
The issue is, are “taxpayers” really deleveraging? If government simply takes the place of the NINJA loans (and I believe that government can actually spend money efficiently and effectively – I am talking about total debt in an ecomony) why should we expect a different result than the great financial crisis? Is the amount of debt that society take on be infinite? Was the US consuming more than it was producing, and isn’t it inevitable that this will end in tears?
Dont get me wrong – as I stated in my “New Suckers” post, I love debt. Loan me a billion dollars…its just that people get all cranky when I don’t pay them back – of course, awful tough to forclose on orgies with strippers, blow, and booze.
Fresno Dan,
“…why exactly is the government paying out more than income sustainable? Is there a profound difference between public versus private debt?”
Indeed there IS a profound difference! If you take out that billion dollar loan, you may be UNABLE to pay. You are the USER of the currency (in this case the US$), and there is a risk that you will default on your debt because you are unable to “get” the dollars you need to service your obligation.
The US government is the ISSUER of the currency. It can always pay. It can never be forced to default due to an inability to “get” the dollar. Government services debt with keystrokes (Bernanke has been most candid on this, explaining to Scott Pelley that purchases are made by “marking up bank accounts”.
Greece, Ireland, Portugal, etc. gave up their sovereign currencies and became USERS of the Euro. It is precisely why they face a debt crisis. The US government remains the ISSUER of its currency and can never become unable to pay. (It can become unwilling to pay, say, because one does not understand ones own monetary system, but that is an entirely different thing.)