Gross: American-style capitalism has reached a dead end but buy T-bills anyway
I must say, Bill Gross is really sour on events in the United States these days. His monthly works are getting more and more populist. And it’s interesting to see how he can segue from his introductory populist screed into a cogent investment analysis.
This month, Gross goes Warren Buffett on us with a Squanderville-like portrait parable of the bankruptcy of American-style capitalism.
There once was a family who lived in a fine house on Main Street USA sometime in the 1980s. It was a handsome house with a big yard and a white picket fence, but something always seemed to be missing. There was never enough of this or that – a fancier car, another TV, it didn’t seem to matter – there was never enough. And so, the house came to be haunted by an unspoken phrase, “there must be more money, there must be more money.” The walls seemed to whisper it in the middle of the night, and even during the day everyone heard it although no one dared say it aloud. The chair spoke, the bedroom armoire, and even five-year-old Billie’s toy rocking horse would eerily demand almost in unison, “there must be more money, there must be more money.”
One day, sensing the family’s distress, little Billie asked his father, “What is it that causes you to have money?” “Well, you go to school, get a good job, and get raises,” his Dad said, “but these days there just doesn’t seem to be enough.” But Billie, being just a little boy didn’t understand and so he went off to ride his rocking horse, searching for the “clue” to “more money.” The horse was a special toy because not only did it whisper like the walls and the living room chair, but it seemed to answer questions if you only rode it fast enough. And so Billie would sit on top of his horse when no one was looking, charging madly up and down, back and forth in a frenzied state to a place where only he and his pony could go. “Take me to where there is money,” he would command his steed.
At first, Billie could not make the horse answer the way it had when he asked about Christmas presents or what kind of ice cream Mom would bring home from the store. Finding money seemed too hard of a question for a toy horse, but it made him try even harder. He would mount it again and again, whipping its head with the leather straps, forcing it faster and faster until it seemed its mouth would foam. “Where is the money, where is the money?” Billie would scream, and at last the horse in full gallop cried out, “borrow the money, borrow the money!”
At just that moment Billie’s Mom came around the corner and into his room and his eyes blazed at her as he fell to the floor. She rushed to his side, but he was unconscious now, yet still whispering the horse’s answer. He continued in that condition for the next 25 years, full grown, and confined comatose to his hospital bed. His family would visit, hoping for his revival, and then miraculously one day in 2008 he awoke with his father and mother at his side. “Did I find the money?” he asked, as if it were still the same afternoon. “Did you borrow it?” “We did,” his Dad answered, “but we borrowed too much.” Billie’s eyes seemed to close at that very instant and he died the next night.
Even as he lay dead, his mother heard his father’s voice saying to her, “My God, we became rich – or what we thought was rich – and we thought that was good, yet now we’re poor and a lost soul of a son to the bad. But poor devil, poor devil, he’s best gone out of a life where he rode to his doom in order to find a rocking horse winner.”
Adapted from a short story by D.H. Lawrence “The Rocking Horse Winner”
Like you, I wondered where this was going and how he was going to tell us this relates to the bond market and investing. So, here’s his transition.
For readers lost in the literative metaphor of another of my lengthy introductions to investment markets, let me connect the dots and suggest that it is symbolic of the perversion of American-style capitalism over the past 30 years – a belief that wealth was a function of printing, lending, and of course borrowing money in order to make more money. Our “horse” required more and more money every year in order to feed asset appreciation, its eventual securitization and the borrowing that both promoted. That horse, like Billie, however, died in 2008 and we face an uncertain and lower growth environment as a result. The uncertainty comes from a number of structural headwinds in PIMCO’s analysis: deleveraging, reregulation, and the forces of deglobalization – most evident now in the markets’ distrust of marginal sovereign credits such as Iceland, Ireland, Greece and a supporting cast of over-borrowed lookalikes. All of them now force bond and capital market vigilantes to make more measured choices when investing long-term monies.
Translation: you can’t just print money and deficit spend to your heart’s content. There will be a day of reckoning for the public sector just there was for the private sector. Gross doesn’t make this distinction, but I am making it. I maintain there is no hard debt constraint for a country that borrows in its own currency (like the United States and unlike Greece and Ireland). Nevertheless, their is a soft constraint, even for large countries. You cannot deficit spend forever. Gross says:
Even though the government’s fist has been successful to date in steadying the destabilizing forces of a delevering private market, investors are now questioning the staying power of public monetary and fiscal policies. 2010 promises to be the year of choosing “which government” can most successfully substitute the governments’ fist for Adam Smith’s invisible hand and for how long? Can individual countries escape a debt crisis by creating even more debt and riding another rocking horse winner? Can the global economy?
This is the same question Gross asked last month, but did not answer (see my post Can you get out of a debt crisis by piling on another layer of debt?). Then, he deferred the answer (apparently until this month), saying only that we are about to witness divergence of developed economy sovereign debt spreads, with many sovereigns trading like corporate debt (i.e. without the famed risk-free appeal).
But, here comes Gross’ own conditionality, which repeats what I said above about borrowing in your own currency but adds other conditions.
The answer, from a vigilante’s viewpoint is “yes,” but a conditional “yes.” There are many conditions and they vary from country to country, but basically it comes down to these:
- Can a country issue its own currency and is it acceptable in global commerce?
- Are a country’s initial conditions (outstanding debt, structural deficit, growth rate, demographic balance) moderate and can it issue future public debt as a substitute for private credit?
- Can a country’s central bank be allowed to reflate via low or negative real interest rates without creating a currency crisis?
These three important conditions render an immediate negative answer when viewed from an investor’s lens focused on Greece for instance: 1) Greece can’t issue debt in its own currency, 2) its initial conditions and demographics are abominable, and 3) its central bank – The ECB – believes in positive, not negative, real interest rates. Greece therefore must extend a beggar’s bowl to the European Union or the IMF because the private market vigilantes have simply had enough. Without guarantees or the promise of long-term assistance, Prime Minister Papandreou’s promise of fiscal austerity falls on deaf ears. Similarly, the Southern European PIGS face a difficult future environment as its walls whisper “the house needs more money, the house needs more money.” It will not come easily, and if it does, it will come at increasingly higher cost, either in the form of higher interest rates, fiscal frugality, or both.
So, what does that mean for sovereign debt? After all, the UK and the US are both large developed sovereigns issuing debt in their own currencies. Both have relatively low federal government debt to GDP.
Perhaps surprisingly, some of the countries on PIMCO’s “must to avoid” list are decently positioned to escape their individual debt crises. The U.K. comes immediately to mind. PIMCO would answer “yes” to all of the three primary conditions outlined earlier for the U.K. in contrast to Greece. We as a firm, however, remain underweight Gilts. The reason is that the debt the U.K. will increasingly issue in the future should lead to inflationary conditions and a depreciating currency relative to other countries, ultimately lowering the realized return on its bonds. If that view becomes consensus, then at some point the U.K. may fail to attain escape velocity from its debt trap. For now though, “crisis” does not describe their current predicament, yet that bed of nitroglycerine must be delicately handled. Avoid the U.K. – there are more attractive choices.
Where else would you put your money? Two months ago, Gross showed us the deficit ring of fire. Then the answer definitely looked like: Finland, Denmark and Australia first, with Norway, Sweden, Germany, Netherlands, and Canada second. But instead he says:
Could one of them be the United States? Well, yes, almost by default to use a poor, but somewhat ironic phrase, because a U.S. Treasury investor must satisfactorily answer “yes” to my three conditions as well, and the U.S. has more favorable demographics and a stronger growth potential than the U.K. – promising a greater chance at escape velocity. But remember – my three conditions just suggest that a country can get out of a debt crisis by creating more debt – they don’t assert that the bonds will be a good investment. Simply comparing Greek or U.K. debt to U.S. Treasury bonds is not the golden ticket to alpha generation in investment markets. U.S. bonds may simply be a “less poor” choice of alternatives.
I’m not buying it for one second. The term "less poor" makes sense. Why would you go with U.S. debt over German or Swedish or Dutch except because of liquidity? Even Gross’ defence of "less poor" sounds god awful.
The reason is complicated, but at its core very simple. As a November IMF staff position note aptly pointed out, high fiscal deficits and higher outstanding debt lead to higher real interest rates and ultimately higher inflation, both trends which are bond market unfriendly. In the U.S. in addition to the 10% of GDP deficits and a growing stock of outstanding debt, an investor must be concerned with future unfunded entitlement commitments which portfolio managers almost always neglect, viewing them as so far off in the future that they don’t matter. Yet should it concern an investor in 30-year Treasuries that the Congressional Budget Office estimates that the present value of unfunded future social insurance expenditures (Social Security and Medicare primarily) was $46 trillion as of 2009, a sum four times its current outstanding debt? Of course it should, and that may be a primary reason why 30-year bonds yield 4.6% whereas 2-year debt with the same guarantee yields less than 1%.
The trend promises to get worse, not better. The imminent passage of health care reform represents a continuing litany of entitlement legislation that will add, not subtract, to future deficits and unfunded liabilities. No investment vigilante worth their salt or outrageous annual bonus would dare argue that current legislation is a deficit reducer as asserted by Democrats and in fact the Congressional Budget Office. Common sense alone would suggest that extending health care benefits to 30 million people will cost a lot of money and that it is being “paid for” in the current bill with standard smoke, and all too familiar mirrors that have characterized such entitlement legislation for decades. An article by an ex-CBO director in The New York Times this past Sunday affirms these suspicions. “Fantasy in, fantasy out,” writes Douglas Holtz-Eakin who held the CBO Chair from 2003–2005. Front-end loaded revenues and back-end loaded expenses promote the fiction that a program that will cost $950 billion over the next 10 years actually reduces the deficit by $138 billion. After all the details are analyzed, Mr. Holtz-Eakin’s numbers affirm a vigilante’s suspicion – it will add $562 billion to the deficit over the next decade. Long-term bondholders beware.
Doesn’t make sense to me except for U.S. investors who want liquidity. Now, I’m not saying bonds can’t rally. I am saying that the U.S. is in worse shape on a relative value basis than Norway or Finland. Gross seems to admit this at the very end.
In today’s marketplace, prudent lending must be directed not only towards sovereigns that can escape a debt trap, but ones that can do so with a minimum of reflationary consequences and currency devaluation – whether it be against other sovereigns or hard assets such as gold. Investment strategies should begin to reflect this preservation of capital principal by positioning bond portfolios on front-ends of selected sovereign yield curve subject to successful reflation (U.S., Brazil) and longer ends of yield curves that can withstand potential debt deflation (Germany, Core Europe). In addition, as increasing debt loads add impetus to higher real interest rates worldwide, a more “unicredit” bond market argues for high quality corporate spread risk as opposed to duration extension. In plain English, that means that a unit of quality credit spread will do better than a unit of duration. Rates face a future bear market as central banks eventually normalize QE policies and 0% yields if global reflation is successful. Spreads in appropriate sovereign and corporate credits are a better bet as long as global contagion is contained. If not, a rush to the safety of Treasury Bills lies ahead.
My read of his final comments is the following:
- More global economic risks are to come, particularly in Europe where Gross mentions debt deflation as a real possibility, something I also see.
- Given these risks, to the degree you are looking at sovereign debt, you want exposure at the short end to those who can reflate successfully i.e. the U.S. and Brazil.
- At the long end, you want sovereign bonds of those countries that can weather a debt deflationary cycle (Germany, Benelux, France).
- In this environment, quality first, then duration.
- Only if reflation is successful and contagion contained, do you want to make some sort of relative value spread play in sovereigns or corporates. Otherwise, stay short and liquid.
In essence, Gross is saying he believes the Eurozone may go into a debt deflation scenario with serious risk for contagion. And while he believes the U.S. will successfully reflate, there is enough risk that you want to be prepared to rush to liquidity.
I think all of this makes sense if only because the U.S. market is liquid. Otherwise, his comments about the UK are equally relevant for the U.S.. His downbeat parable of U.S. profligacy does not square with the substance of his investment opinion.
Source
Rocking-Horse Winner – Bill Gross, Pimco
Gross says the US can reflate but implies the UK can’t. The inference is that this “makes sense if only because the U.S. market is liquid.”
My inference is that this is not liquidity. It is that the US can rescue its banks as their obligations are USD. British banks have external liabilities valued in the trillions of USD. So Britain is will succumb if they have a bout of debt deflation while the US can save its banking sector and reflate.
You are not reading my statement accurately. I said his talk of T-bills
only makes sense because he believes they are a liquid market. What I mean
by that is that he mentions all of the unfunded liabilities. But then
suggests T-bills anyway. He then suggests that we could have some sort of
market contagion that creates a flight into liquid assets as we saw during
the panic of 2008. So I am inferring he likes T-bills not because the US is
better but because they are liquid.
I am not comparing the US ability to reflate versus the UK’s.
I understand your point, but I understood it when I read your original post. I think it’s more likely that I was unclear in my comment.
You conclude your post with this:
“I think all of this makes sense if only because the U.S. market is liquid. Otherwise, his comments about the UK are equally relevant for the U.S.”
You are taking his conclusions favoring short US Treasuries and eschewing UK Gilts, and concluding the key differentiator is liquidity. I agree that this is a possible differentiator, but I disagree that it is the only possible one. I would point more toward the categorization as the US as being able to reflate, and not the UK (by implication).
This is not something that Gross delves into. After all his article however informative is a client retention and recruitment device. I suspect his dislike of Gilts is rooted in external financial sector liabilities. The US can recapitalize its banks, but it is questionable whether the UK could in a regime of falling exchange rates. Meaning, a currency problem can cause a banking problem and therefore deflation. Whether one thinks this is a likely outcome or not, I suspect that UK sovereign debt yields too little to compensate for this risk.
Is this more clear? Hopefully I am not misreading you at this point.