The world has experienced three periods of extreme financial dislocation in the past century, 1929, 1973, and 1990. Two of these have been deflationary. While most observers have their eyes firmly peeled on 1973 and its aftermath, 1929 and 1990 are the scenarios of greatest concern today. These deflationary periods should be instructive as to what the worst case scenario is in this financial crisis as debt deflation is the longer term risk. I will examine 1929 from a U.S. perspective. 1973 from a UK perspective and 1990 from a Japanese perspective as these were the economies hardest hit in each of these episodes.
1929
Pre-Depression financial speculation led to an apocalyptic collapse that ushered in a period of severe economic contraction globally. Most economists, including the likes of Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke, accept the Milton Friedman version of events — that the Depression was a result of insufficient monetary liquidity. The belief is that the Federal Reserve and other central banks stuck to the ‘hard money’ dogma of the gold standard and failed to supply adequate liquidity to banks. This is why the U.S. suffered a massive wave of bank failures while there were virtually none in countries like Canada and the UK.
1973
The problem in 1973 was commodity prices and inflation. The common belief is that monetary authorities, still remembering 1929 and its debt deflation, failed to stem the tide of rising inflation which ravaged the world’s economies for nearly a decade in a wage-price spiral.
1990
Ben Bernanke, student of the Great Depression, believes that Japan suffered a loss decade because monetary authorities failed to react quickly enough to deflationary threats in the economy. He is nicknamed ‘Helicopter Ben’ for the following pronouncement he gave in talking about the U.S. avoiding a Japanese scenario in 2002:
The U.S. government has a technology, called a printing press — or, today, its electronic equivalent — that allows it to produce as many U.S. dollars as it wishes at essentially no cost.
–Ben Bernanke November 22, 2002
Today’s Fear: 1973
So, the obvious question is: which horrible period of declining asset values and financial turmoil is most frightening today and what can we do to make sure we avoid it? From recent pronouncements by officals at the three most prestigious central banks, the ECB (European Central Bank), the U.S. Federal Reserve, and the BoE (Bank of England), we can safely assume 1973 is the model they are most concerned about. Everybody fears inflation right now. But, what if that’s not the problem?
See, 1973 didn’t have the extremes of credit and debt that we see today and saw in 1929 and in 1990 Japan. 1973 was a case of too much monetary liquidity (true inflation) spilling over into price inflation. On the other hand 1929 and 1990, were cases of too much monetary liquidity creating a debt bubble and spilling over into asset inflation. The central difference is the debt.
The Real Problem: Debt Deflation
Debt is a special problem because we live in a fractional reserve banking system. Murray Rothbard, one of the most esteemed economists of the Austrian School, said:
“The Ricardian analysis of the business cycle went something as follows: The natural moneys emerging as such on the world free market are useful commodities, generally gold and silver. If money were confined to these commodities, then the economy would work in the aggregate as it does in particular markets: A smooth adjustment of supply and demand, and therefore no cycles of boom and bust. But the injection of bank credit adds another crucial and disruptive element. For banks expand credit and therefore bank money in the form of notes or deposits which are theoretically redeemable on demand in gold, but in practice clearly are not.”
–“Economic Depressions: Their Cause and Cure,” Murray Rothbard
Basically, Rothbard is saying that inflating available credit through banks’ lending money they don’t have creates a natural boom-bust cycle. Banks go overboard at some point in time, banks suffer credit losses, banks then become more conservative, and credit contracts accordingly.
So when debt is high relative to GDP and disposable income, when debt servicing costs are high relative to income, the contraction of credit is a problem. When credit contracts and banks lend neither to one another or to customers out of fear and in order to protect their own assets, people go bankrupt. This infects the real economy and in turn creates more bad debt, which causes banks to contract credit further in a negative feedback loop. So-called money velocity goes down.
This is what happened to Japan in 1990 and what happened to the U.S. in 1929. Economic stimulus in the form of easy money has no effect on this process because low interest rates and monetary liquidity cannot force people to lend or borrow when credit is contracting. This is also what is happening right now in the UK and in the US. These two countries have much too much debt and cannot take on further credit. Easy money is no panacea because it cannot counteract the inherent deleveraging of an overleveraged financial sector.
What to do?
The Japanese problem is instructive as it actually demonstrates more that easy money is not the way forward. The Nordic Bubble workout of the early 1990s may be the best paradigm for a worried Fed and BoE.
Ultimately, it is the political solutions that will make this crisis longer and deeper.
Update: See post on Japanese stock market crash charts at Chart of the day: Japan 1984-2004
Other posts on Japan can be found under the label ‘Japan‘.
Sources and Additional Reading
The Austrian Theory of the Trade Cycle, Ludwig von Mises, Gottfried Haberler, Murray Rothbard, Friedrich Hayek
A History of the Modern British Isles 1914-1999, Arthur Marwick
Panic on Wall Street, Robert Sobel
A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960, Milton Friedman and Anna Jacobson Schwartz
The World in Depression 1929-1939, Charles Kindleberger
Manias, Panics, and Crashes, Charles Kindleberger,
Devil Take The Hindmost, Edward Chancellor
Japan as Number One, Ezra Vogel
The Bubble Economy, Christopher Wood